Market Clearing#

\(M+3\) markets must clear in OG-Core—the labor market, the private capital market, the government bond market, and \(M\) goods markets. By Walras’ Law, we only need to use \(M+2\) of those market clearing conditions because the remaining one is redundant. In the model, we choose to use the labor, private capital, government bond market, and the first \(M-1\) goods market clearing conditions and to ignore the \(M\)th goods market clearing condition. But we present all \(M+3\) market clearing conditions here. Further, the redundant \(M\)th goods market clearing condition—sometimes referred to as the resource constraint—makes for a nice check on the solution method to see if everything worked.

We also characterize here the law of motion for total bequests \(BQ_t\). Although it is not technically a market clearing condition, one could think of the bequests law of motion as the bequests market clearing condition.

Market Clearing Conditions#

The sections below detail the labor, government debt, private capital, and \(M\) goods market clearing conditions of the model in the baseline case of a large partially open economy.

Labor market clearing#

Labor market clearing (110) requires that aggregate labor demand \(\sum_{m=1}^M L_{m,t}\) measured in efficiency units equal the sum of household efficiency labor supplied \(e_{j,s}n_{j,s,t}\).

(110)#\[ \sum_{m=1}^M L_{m,t} = \sum_{s=E+1}^{E+S}\sum_{j=1}^{J} \omega_{s,t}\lambda_j e_{j,s}n_{j,s,t} \quad \forall t\]

Capital markets generalities#

Before describing the government bond market and private capital market clearing conditions, respectively, we define some general capital market conditions relative to both markets. Both the government bond market and private capital market are characterized by interest rates that differ exogenously. As described in (94), the interest rate at which the government repays debt or earns on surpluses \(r_{gov,t}\) differs from the marginal product of capital \(r_t\) by an exogenous wedge. And the marginal product of capital is determined in equilibrium \(r_t\) (except in the closed economy case). But we make a simplifying assumption that households are indifferent regarding the allocation of their savings between holding government debt or investing in private capital.[1] And we assume that this indifference exists in spite of the difference in relative returns between \(r_{gov,t}\) and \(r_{K,t}\). We define total domestic household savings in a given period as \(B_t\).

(111)#\[ B_t \equiv \sum_{s=E+2}^{E+S+1}\sum_{j=1}^{J}\Bigl(\omega_{s-1,t-1}\lambda_j b_{j,s,t} + i_s\omega_{s,t-1}\lambda_j b_{j,s,t}\Bigr) \quad \forall t\]

And total domestic household savings is constrained to be allocated between domestic private capital ownership \(K^d_t\) and domestic holdings of government bonds \(D^d_t\).

(112)#\[ K^d_t + D^d_t = B_t \quad \forall t\]

Government bond market clearing#

The government in OG-Core can run deficits or surpluses each period, as shown in equation (88) in Section Government Budget Constraint. Because the government can borrow or save on net each period \(D_t\), someone must lend or borrow those assets on the supply side.

We assume that foreigners hold a fixed percentage of new domestic government debt issuance. Let \(D_{t+1} - D_t\) be the total new issuance government debt, and let \(D^f_{t+1} - D^f_t\) be the amount of those new issuances held by foreigners. We assume that foreign holdings of new government issuances of debt \(D^f_{t+1}-D^f_t\) are an exogenous percentage \(\zeta_D\in[0,1]\) of total new government debt issuances. This percentage \(\zeta_D\) is something we calibrate.

(113)#\[ D^{f}_{t+1} = D^{f}_{t} + \zeta_{D}(D_{t+1} - D_{t}) \quad\forall t\]

The government debt market clearing condition is the following, where total domestic government debt \(D_t\) equals the amount of that debt held by domestic households \(D^d_t\) plus the amount of that debt held by foreign households \(D^f_t\).

(114)#\[ D_t = D^d_t + D^f_t \quad\forall t\]

We discuss the meaning of different permutations of the \(\zeta_D\) parameter corner solutions \(\zeta_D=0\) and \(\zeta_D=1\) in Chapter Open Economy Options. If \(\zeta_D=0\), we are assuming a closed economy government bond market in which all new government debt is held by domestic households and in which all government debt in the long-run (steady-state) is held by domestic households \(\bar{D}^f=0\).

Private capital market clearing#

Domestic firms in each industry \(m\) rent private capital \(K_t\equiv\sum_{m=1}^M K_{m,t}\) from domestic households \(K^d_t\) and from foreign investors \(K^f_t\).

(115)#\[K_t = K^d_t + K^f_t \quad\forall t \quad\text{where}\quad K_t \equiv \sum_{m=1}^M K_{m,t}\]

Assume that there exists some exogenous world interest rate \(r^*_t\). We assume that foreign capital supply \(K^f_t\) is an exogenous percentage \(\zeta_K\in[0,1]\) of the excess total domestic private capital demand \(ED^{K,r^*}_t\) that would exist if domestic private capital demand were determined by the exogenous world interest rate \(r^*_t\) and domestic private capital supply were determined by the model consistent return on household savings \(r_{p,t}\). This percentage \(\zeta_K\) is something we calibrate. Define excess total domestic capital demand at the exogenous world interest rate \(r^*_t\) as \(ED^{K,r^*}_t\), where \(K^{r^*}_t\equiv\sum_{m=1}^M K^{r^*}_{m,t}\) is the capital demand by domestic firms at the world interest rate \(r^*_t\), and \(K^{d}_t\) is the domestic supply of private capital to firms, which is modeled as being a function of the actual rate faced by households \(r_{p,t}\). Then our measure of excess demand at the world interest rate is the following.

(116)#\[ ED^{K,r^*}_t \equiv K^{r^*}_t - K^d_t \quad\forall t \quad\text{where}\quad K^{r^*}_t\equiv \sum_{m=1}^M K^{r^*}_{m,t}\]

Then we assume that total foreign private capital supply \(K^f_t\) is a fixed fraction of this excess capital demand at the world interest rate \(r^*\).

(117)#\[ K^{f}_t = \zeta_{K}ED^{K,r^*}_t \quad\forall t\]

This approach nicely nests the small open economy specification discussed in Section Small Open Economy of Chapter Open Economy Options in which \(\zeta_K=1\), foreigners flexibly supply all the excess demand for private capital, the marginal product of capital is fixed at the exogenous world interest rate \(r^*\), and domestic households face the least amount of crowd out by government debt. The opposite extreme is the closed private capital market assumption of \(\zeta_K=0\) in which \(K^f_t=0\) and households must supply all the capital demanded in the domestic market. In this specification, the interest rate is the most flexible and adjusts to equilibrate domestic private capital supply \(K^d_t\) with private capital demand \(K_t\).

For the intermediate specifications of \(\zeta_K\in(0,1)\), foreigners provide a fraction of the excess demand defined in (116). This allows for partial inflows of foreign private capital, partial crowd-out of government spending on private investment, and partial adjustment of the domestic interest rate \(r_t\). This latter set of model specifications could be characterized as large-open economy or partial capital mobility.

Goods market clearing#

All \(M\) industry goods markets must clear. Total demand of production good \(m\) for consumption can be written as a function of total household demand for each consumption good \(i\)

(118)#\[ C_{m,t} = \sum_{i=1}^{I} \pi_{i,m} C_{i,t} \quad\forall t \quad\text{and}\quad m=1,2,...M\]

where

(119)#\[ C_{i,t} \equiv \sum_{s=E+1}^{E+S}\sum_{j=1}^{J}\omega_{s,t}\lambda_j c_{i,j,s,t} \quad\forall i,t\]

Because we make a simplifying assumption that only the \(M\)th industry output can be used as investment, government spending, or government debt, consumption demand equals total output of good \(m\) in the first \(M-1\) industries.

(120)#\[ Y_{m,t} = C_{m,t} \quad\forall t \quad\text{and}\quad m=1,2,...M-1\]

The output of the \(M\)th industry can be used for private investment, infrastructure investment, government spending, and government debt.[2] As such, the market clearing condition in the \(M\)th industry will look more like the traditional \(Y=C+I+G+NX\) expression.[3]

(121)#\[ Y_{M,t} = C_{M,t} + I_{M,t} + I_{g,t} + G_t + r_{p,t} K^f_t + r_{p,t}D^f_t - (K^f_{t+1} - K^f_t) - \bigl(D^f_{t+1} - D^f_t\bigr) - RM_t \quad\forall t\]

where

(122)#\[\begin{split} I_{M,t} &\equiv \sum_{m=1}^M K_{m,t+1} - (1 - \delta_{M,t})\sum_{m=1}^M K_{m,t} \quad\forall t \\ &= K_{t+1} - (1 - \delta_{M,t})K_t \\ &= (K^d_{t+1} + K^f_{t+1}) - (1 - \delta_{M,t})(K^d_t + K^f_t)\end{split}\]

In the partially open economy, we must add to the right-hand-side of (121) the output paid to the foreign owners of capital \(r_{p,t} K^f_t\) and to the foreign holders of government debt \(r_{p,t}D^f_t\). And we must subtract off the foreign inflow component \(K^f_{t+1} - K^f_t\) from private capital investment as shown in the first term in parentheses on the right-hand-side of (121). You can see in the definition of private investment (122) where this amount of foreign capital is part of \(I_{M,t}\).

Similarly, we must subtract off the foreign purchases of new government debt \(D^f_{t+1} - D^f_t\) and aggregate remittances \(RM_t\) as shown in the second term in parentheses and the last term, respectively, on the right-hand-side of (121). The new foreign purchases of government debt are part of \(I_{g,t}\) and \(G_t\), as they are functions of GDP \(Y_t\), as shown in (89), (90), and the government budget constraint (88). Foreign lending relaxes the resource constraint. And aggregate remittances are part of aggregate consumption \(C_t\) and also relax the resource constraint.

Net exports (imports) of capital in the form of foreign private capital inflows \(K^f_t\), foreign holdings of government debt \(D^f_t\), and remittances \(RM_t\) are clearly accounted for in (121). Foreign remittances received by domestic households are described in Section Remittances of Chapter Households.

Total Bequests Law of Motion#

Total bequests \(BQ_t\) are the collection of savings of household from the previous period who died at the end of the period. These savings are augmented by the interest rate because they are returned after being invested in the production process.

(123)#\[ BQ_{t} = (1+r_{p,t})\left(\sum_{s=E+2}^{E+S+1}\sum_{j=1}^J\rho_{s-1}\lambda_j\omega_{s-1,t-1}b_{j,s,t}\right) \quad\forall t\]

Because the form of the period utility function in (33) ensures that \(b_{j,s,t}>0\) for all \(j\), \(s\), and \(t\), total bequests will always be positive \(BQ_{j,t}>0\) for all \(j\) and \(t\).

Footnotes#

This section contains the footnotes for this chapter.